I agree with that, but it's a strongly-debated point. After all, if
the current government is doing lots of bad things, wouldn't it be
good to have someone even slightly better in? The lesser of two evils,
as the cliché goes. So why doesn't sacrificing principle for
power work?
Here's my theory as to why things work out that way, with
diagrams.
Some simplifications, and why they're okay
Okay, so let's start by making a big simplification: we'll just
consider one political issue, and assume that it's one that strongly
influences people's votes. In practice, the effect below tends to
happen to lots of policies together, so it's not an important
simplification - when you consider every issue at once, the same thing
happens. The members of the electorate then have various opinions
about what the solution to this issue looks like, which are
distributed in some sort of distribution.
I've drawn this with "left" and "right" because I think the diagram
is more readable that way than with "up" and "down". There's not
necessarily any connection on this issue with the traditional
left-wing and right-wing positions, though, and the argument I'm
making will generalise to issues where the options can't be expressed
on a linear scale1, or indeed in Euclidean geometry.
Diagram 1: A
distribution of opinion. Somewhere between normal, flat, and lumpy.
Exactly what the distribution looks like doesn't really
matter. There are usually going to be more people around the middle
than at the edges, and it's not going to be completely smooth -
there'll be peaks here and there that represent popular solutions.
Let's also assume that in general people vote for political parties
close to their own opinions where possible. There's plenty of room for
misinformation about who actually supports what policy to creep in,
but since both sides are trying it the net effect is going to be
relatively minor.
Let's also assume a 2-party system with a non-proportional2
electoral system that makes it very hard for a third party to break in
anywhere, as we have in the UK (even with the rise of the Lib Dems) or
in the USA. This is a fair assumption because it's what we have.
So, next picture: two of the big peaks of opinion distribution near
the centre are occupied by the major political parties - the Oranges
and the Carrots.
Diagram 2: Same as the first, but with the Orange party occupying the peak to the left of the centre, and the Carrot party occupying the peak to the right of it.
There's then a general election. The Orange party loses the election,
and the Carrots party enters government.
Why running to the centre works in the short-term
This is the point where the "principles or power" argument comes in
to play. Obviously, it's really bad for the Carrot party to be in
power. There's no real hope of another party coming out of nowhere to
save the day, at least not by next election, so to get the Carrots
out, the Oranges have to get in. But the electorate has just been
presented with the Oranges, and didn't like them - it preferred the
Carrot policies3.
So, to "be more electable", the Oranges move their policy along a
bit towards the centre.
Diagram 3: The Carrot party is still on the right peak, but the Oranges have moved their position into the valley between the two peaks.
At the next election, the centre point between the Orange policy
and the Carrot policy is in a different place. The key swing voters in
between the two parties are now going to cast their votes a bit
differently, with the Oranges picking up more of their votes than
before. They might lose a few votes from the left-most end of the
distribution, too, but they can afford to: votes they lose from the
left go to an inconsequential rival or abstentions. Votes they take
from the right come off their major opponent's totals. They can afford
to lose almost twice as many votes from the left as they gain from the
right and still come out ahead.
For instance, if there are 100 voters in all, and 53 voted Carrot
and 47 voted Orange, then by convincing 10 Carrot voters to vote
Orange, the scores become 43-57. A 6 vote margin has been changed to a
14 vote margin in the other direction. If Orange loses 12 voters from
their left as a result, they're still 2 votes ahead of the Carrots at
43-45, despite losing more voters than they gained.
So, by following this strategy, the Oranges are able to regain
power at the next election.
So why doesn't everyone just end up in the centre?
Over in a formerly-smoke-filled but now nicely air-conditioned room
at Carrot Headquarters, the party green-wigs need to decide on a
strategy. They have two choices.
- They can do what the Oranges did to them, and move closer to the centre, to try to retake power. There's not a lot of spare space to move into, though, without dropping this as an election issue at all, which won't actually do them much good. And you need to have some space to manouevre for the 2:1 multiplier you get from winning swing voters to actually be possible.
- They can take a longer-term view, and move their own position to the right. That's probably closer to where they wanted it to be anyway, before an earlier pragmatic Carrot leader decided that on top of the peak was a good place to be.
Diagram 4: The Carrot party has also moved off its peak to the right, re-opening a wider gap between the two parties.
The Carrots pick option 2, and lose the next election too. There's
probably some internal squabbles at this point, but they wait them
out.
... and then, the plan pays off.
Because public opinion is not static. It's fluid, and on some
issues it can change really quickly in the right circumstances. Like
advertising, if you say something for long enough to enough people,
some of them will listen, and change their minds. If a party states a
particular policy, its supporters become more likely to support that
policy.
Consider, for instance, at this
YouGov poll (PDF) from December. On page 7, there's a question
about whether short prison sentences or community sentences are more
effective.
In general, imprisonment is the stereotypical Conservative
policy. They have the reputation for being "tougher on crime". So it
was in some ways an unexpected announcement of Conservative policy
that they would want to go for community sentences. In the poll,
though, Conservative voters split 36:44 in favour of community
sentences.
Perhaps the stereotypes are wrong? Public opinion often isn't what
it's claimed to be. Are the Conservatives playing to their base after
all?
This time, though, there's something else at work: compare that poll to this other poll (PDF), also carried out by YouGov, only a month earlier.
In this poll, Conservative voters are split 57:35 against
the use of community sentences. In a month, there has been a
30 point swing in Conservative voter
opinion. Additionally, there has been a 19 point swing in general
voter opinion (which includes the Conservatives). From being a policy
that had the weight of public opinion against it - and think tanks
warning the government away from it - it's now one that the public is
roughly split on.
There are differences of question wording between the two polls,
but these mainly consist of the later poll having a tiny neutral
summary of the purported advantages of each choice (which I don't
think is particularly significant), and the later poll attributing the
community sentences policy to the current government (which may well
be a significant wording difference, but one that strengthens my point
if it is)
I don't think public opinion is quite that fluid on most issues -
sentencing policy is in general not an issue of major importance to
most voters - and in general that sort of change takes years or
decades rather than weeks, but it definitely happens over time.
So, how does this affect the diagram?
Diagram 5:
The distribution of public opinion has shifted, with the peaks moved
towards the parties' new positions.
The next election, the Carrots win it, by about the same margin as
they won the election back in Diagram 1.
So, the Oranges have to do something. It worked last time, so they
move their policy off the peak, and closer to the Carrots.
After a couple of cycles of this, what happens is of course that
the Oranges have ended up fairly close to where the Carrots were
originally. At this point, the Carrots can start moving slowly back
towards the Oranges, both picking up votes themselves, and trying to
make the new consensus one
that sticks so that they don't have to defend it in future. The
result: the Carrots have spent a fair proportion of the time in power,
the Oranges will be implementing their policies anyway while the
Carrots are out of power, and the Carrots can direct their energies to
winning the next argument.
It took a little more than a single election cycle, but the Carrots
have most definitely - by sticking to their principles - won. This is
why, as Broadsnark said:
The people whose power lasts are those whose power comes from their principles, not from selling their principles out. It’s not naive to think that people shouldn’t sell their principles to power. It’s naive to think that someone in power who has sold their principles can do us any good.
So, the Oranges have power - and are using it to implement Carrot
policy. Whether they count this as a success depends entirely on
whether they went into politics to get power or to advance their
principles. Meanwhile, the people who liked the Oranges' initial
policy are stuck out on their own, without any formal representation,
and now have to work hard to draw the Oranges (and ideally the
Carrots, too) back towards them.
I've given this example with political parties, but it really works
for anyone trying to make a difference to anything - in the long term,
the successful people are people who've convinced opinion to follow
them.
What if the Carrots are really bad?
Some governments are so bad that even letting them be in power for
one term is going to be disastrous, and it's worth paying a high price
to keep them out. The problem with this argument is that you can't
keep them out forever.
Governments in the UK lose an average of 3 points of popular vote
between elections. Virtually none have actually gained
popularity between elections. Sooner or later, the accumulated
frustrations of the population are going to kick them out no matter
how well they're doing.
The opposition will be back in power eventually and you can't stop
this. It's not worth delaying it a few years if the cost is
implementing their policies anyway.
There are in a democracy ways other than being the official
opposition to make it politically unviable for the government to do
something, anyway.
(This only applies if you trust the opposition to hold another fair
election, of course, but if you don't there are bigger problems)
Wouldn't this just lead to no-one compromising on anything, and nothing getting done?
Maybe.
In practice, though, no. There's a major difference between
compromising on what gets implemented now, and compromising on your
underlying principles.
To illustrate this, say there are two issues (A and B), with three possible policies (A0, A1 and A2, with A1 being 'between' the other two policies, and similarly for B).
If A2 is the current situation, a supporter of
A0 could team up and compromise with supporters of
A1 to get A1. It's not what they actually want,
but it's closer to it. And if between them they can make A1
stick, then maybe in a few years it'll be possible to get mass support
for moving to A0.
This is a good compromise, and isn't inconsistent with having
principles and keeping them.
Suppose, then, that this support of A0 also supports
B0. The current situation is A1 and
B1. A supporter of A2 and B0 offers
to help with getting B0 in exchange for help in getting
A2.
Assuming that A and B are both major issues - if A is "who pays for
lunch?" and B is "should we invade Norway?", this doesn't hold - this
is a bad compromise. To take it, the principle of A0 will
have to be sacrificed.
In between the two is an offer to support B0 if you
don't campaign for A0 and accept A1 as
sufficient (assuming A1 is currently true) - at least in
public.
I think this is still generally a bad deal - both sides of the deal
want (or at least, aren't opposed to) B0 already. So you
could probably get B0 another way without giving up the
possibility of A0. There might be cases where it's worth
taking, though, if B0 is likely to be the sticky position,
and so you can go back to working towards A0 relatively
quickly once B0 is done.
The reason that the good compromises are good is that they don't
stop you working on moving mass opinion towards your position. The
reason the bad compromises are bad is that you have to shut up and
contribute towards making things worse, which means that when you
decide you've had enough, you've been digging your own hole for the
last few years and have to fill that in first.
Only making good compromises means that political alliances on one
issue aren't necessarily going to be the same as the political
alliances on a different issue. There's nothing wrong with that,
either, though it can take some getting used to.
Conclusion
The way to win, in the long-term, is to have principles, to stick
to them, and to argue for them consistently and convincingly. There
are plenty of situations where the short-term gain is from abandoning
some principles to help others: beware.
Having short-term political power, in the way the default thinks of
"political" and "power" is not necessarily useful, and may in some
cases be actively counter-productive to principled success because the
costs of getting it are too high.
Footnotes
1 If I was better at drawing, there would be a picture
of an opinion surface in two dimensions to demonstrate this. Please
imagine your own.
2 In a proportional system, the incentives are
different, and the advantages to sticking to your principles are much
clearer. It's the main reason that I want one.
3 Not necessarily true in a non-proportional system, but
let's assume that like the UK and USA, the tendency is to expand
differences in the popular vote, rather than reduce them. Elections
where the winner of the most seats and the winner of the popular vote
differ will result in a very different - and generally messier -
political dynamic anyway.